The Dispatch
Share this post
The Unforgiving Math of the U.S. Labor Market
thedispatch.com

The Unforgiving Math of the U.S. Labor Market

We are missing somewhere between 4 million and 7 million workers, and even if we could find them it might not fix our problem.

Brent Orrell
Mar 4
Comment86
Share
(Photo by Olivier Douliery/AFP/Getty Images.)

Two new reports on the condition of the U.S. labor market point out just how big a challenge America has in keeping its economy staffed. The first, by Emsi labor market economist Ron Hetrick along with Cassondra Martinez and Hannah Grieser, focuses attention on the underlying building blocks of the labor market: demographic pressures, a pandemic-fueled rush to retirement, and collapsing immigration rates as our chief challenges. The second, a paper by Harvard economists Alex Domash and Larry Summers, precisely quantifies the sources of the labor shortage and connects it to rising inflation. The full picture suggests that concerns about a wage-price inflation spiral are well justified.

Emsi’s new analysis builds on its 2021 report, The Demographic Drought: how the approaching sansdemic will transform the labor market for the rest of our lives. That report, which I wrote about here, was an economic retelling of how declining fertility is colliding with accelerating retirements to make labor shortages a permanent feature of American economic life. Emsi’s new report narrows this analysis and applies it to immediate post-COVID-19 conditions. While our working age population is still growing, it isn’t growing nearly fast enough to keep pace with general population growth or labor market demand. The authors chalk up the gap to COVID-related work hesitancy, early retirements, childcare shortages, too-generous public subsidies for non-work, and a precipitous drop in immigration levels. To return us to pre-pandemic employment levels, we need 875,000 more workers right now. To get us to a steady-state workforce that catches up with the demands of a growing population and economy, we need around 3.2 million more workers, a figure that will continue to grow over time.

The largest chunk of “missing” workers—those who were in the workforce before COVID-19 and arguably should be now—is accounted for by 2.6 million early retirements in the over-55 demographic. Lower immigration levels are another significant factor. Legal immigration reached a recent peak of just more than1 million in 2015 before falling to just over 200,000 in 2021. Counterintuitively, anti-immigration sentiment spiked precisely as immigration was collapsing . A recent Gallup poll found that 35 percent of Americans want less immigration (compared to 19 percent in 2021) while the number of Americans who support more immigration fell from 15 percent to 9 percent. This suggests that trying to solve the labor shortage by welcoming more workers from abroad—one of the fastest ways to grow the labor pool—continues to face significant political hurdles.

The Domash and Summers analysis is useful for understanding how demographics and labor flows are affecting wages and inflation. They begin by saying the standard unemployment measures are less helpful in understanding labor market tightness than “firm-side” vacancy and quit-rate measures. Our nominal unemployment rate as of January was 4 percent, indicating modest slack in the labor force. Firm-side data tells a different story. Using historically high levels of openings and job quits, Domash and Summers say the functional unemployment rate is below 2 percent. While varying in degrees of importance, they attribute labor market tightness to many (but not all) the same factors as Hetrick, spreading it relatively evenly across excess retirements, COVID health concerns, immigration, and demographics.

Source: Domash/Summers, How Tight Are U.S. Labor Markets?

One interesting point of departure between the two papers is the relative emphasis the authors place on the role of public subsidies like stimulus payments and more generous pandemic unemployment insurance compensation. Unlike Emsi, which points to record high, stimulus-driven savings rates as a key factor keeping people out of the workforce, Domash and Summers offer a more complex analysis. Workers, they say, are signaling that money may not be at the forefront of their considerations right now. Instead (or, perhaps, in addition), they say, workers “tastes” have changed with increasing demands for more flexible working arrangements and, at times, different work altogether. The authors cite recent polling that shows nearly half of U.S. workers are reconsidering the type of job they want. Twenty-six percent want a job that provides remote or hybrid working options. Nearly 40 percent of workers say they would consider quitting if they couldn’t work from home. Combined, these factors have increased the “reservation wage” (i.e. the wage below which workers will decline employment) by 9.3 percent. Tight labor markets make for choosey workers, and choosey workers lead to tighter, less predictable (some would say, frantic) labor markets with workers churning through multiple jobs in search of higher wages and better benefits. 

Depending on your perspective this is either a virtuous or vicious cycle, or perhaps a virtuous cycle that has turned sour. Especially for those at the lower end of the labor market, nominal wages have risen fast, as much as 4.5 percent since December 2020. That is the fastest since 1983, but those gains are being offset by inflation in the prices of goods and services they purchase which is trending as high as 6.8 percent, a 39-year high. All things considered, recent analysis shows all sectors have below trend in real wage growth compared to pre-pandemic. This sort of trend hits those at the lower end of the wage scale the hardest because they spend the largest portion of their income on consumable goods. Without stabilizing the labor supply chiefly through persuading people to “unretire” or figuring out how to import more workers from abroad without setting off a political firestorm, the case for a wage-price spiral begins to look more compelling.

And here’s the real kicker: Assuming we could grow the labor force, Domash and Summers say, it would, in good hamster-wheel fashion, inject more money into the economy and raise aggregate demand for goods and services, leaving us no better off in terms of spending-driven inflationary pressures. The solution, then, lies not just in growing the workforce but in raising productivity, getting more goods and services per hour of labor expended. While some predict other changes like increased work-from-home arrangements may boost productivity over the long term, productivity growth has remained stubbornly low over the past several decades.

Economics is the “dismal science” because progress in raising real incomes and increasing wealth is a pain-staking process, built on unpredictable and serendipitous developments, and filled with trap doors and feedback loops that can turn negative. These challenges mean paying people more, by itself, can neither raise real incomes nor solve our labor shortage. We need to focus on the basics: encouraging flexible working arrangements that keep workers engaged and productive longer, leveraging technology to improve productivity, engaging “hidden workers” to grow labor supply, and improving skill levels across the board so that the amazing American jobs machine continues to work its rising-living standards magic.

Comment86
ShareShare

Create your profile

0 subscriptions will be displayed on your profile (edit)

Skip for now

Only Dispatch Members only can comment on this post

Already a paid subscriber? Sign in

Check your email

For your security, we need to re-authenticate you.

Click the link we sent to , or click here to sign in.

CatoTheElder
Mar 4

Good analysis, as far as it goes. Which is not far enough, I’m afraid. There’s pitiful consideration—barely even mention, actually—of the kinds of jobs on offer, especially if we ignore the simple and understandable desire to work more from home.

Many of the jobs available are of the low-pay, low-esteem, “Would you like fries with that?” sort. There is a growing trend amongst younger people, who already see the prosperity of previous generations evaporating in front of them, and now the disturbing specter of inflation erasing the gains of higher wages before a job is even accepted, toward rejection of what one might call “labor of the oppressed”. It’s rare for people to enjoy jobs in the fast food sector, or as clerks in quick-trip-style shops where one goes from schlocking beer and processing cards paying for gas one moment to selling beer and frozen burritos the next, all the while knowing that when a break in the action does come, there’s the floor to mop. And don’t get me going on call center jobs, janitorial/custodial positions, or the shockingly bad pay offered to those who provide “skilled care” to our sick, elderly, and disabled at home. Paying people peanuts to take care of bed sores and change adult diapers is, frankly, to insult the worker, whom we too often claim should be pleased and proud to have the opportunity to do “honest work” with “dignity”.

We need to look much more closely, and with more widely open eyes, at what kind of society we have put together, how it functions, and our expectations thereof and therein. We are headed the wrong direction. Going that direction faster will not improve things much, and little if at all in any good and lasting fashion.

Expand full comment
Reply
46 replies
Don Harban
Mar 4

One of the factors driving people to not come back to work could be the discovery that the satisfaction consumers find in the "next increment" of consumption is diminishing while the effort that they must exert to obtain that satisfaction is increasing. The last two years has found us virtually divorced from some of that consumption and MAYBE realizing that we can happily accept "less" in exchange for doing less.

In addition, the notion that we would "rather do it at home" might not be so much a reflection of the satisfaction of working at home as a dissatisfaction with the evolution of how we "work at work". It might be that loyalty and pride in our employers is vanishing. Certainly employment in my now finished career has evolved from "lifetime" relationships to "mayfly courtships". I wonder how many of the new AWOL's would look forward to going back to work if their employers knew their names. I wonder how many would have come back if the employers hadn't created an understand that their employees would be "dropped like a bad habit" on the first cloudy day.

And while I am fully cognizant of the need to ensure gender and racial respect, I wonder how many would return if employers reduced the intrigue that accompanies the threat of "cancellation" for employees inadvertently saying the wrong word.

When I was working I couldn't wait to get together with my workmates -- even when things were tough. Today, workers are set together as adversaries and regarded as interchangeable cogs in a machine. Why would anyone who has a better choice bother to get out of the driveway.

Expand full comment
Reply
3 replies
84 more comments…
TopNewCommunity

No posts

Ready for more?

© 2022 The Dispatch
Privacy ∙ Terms ∙ Collection notice
Publish on Substack Get the app
Substack is the home for great writing